Mancur Olson
Mançur Olson | |
---|---|
Born | Mançur Lloyd Olson Jr. January 22, 1932 Grand Forks, North Dakota, U.S. |
Died | Script error: The function "death_date_and_age" does not exist. College Park, Maryland, U.S. |
Nationality | American |
Institution | University of Maryland Princeton University |
Field | Institutional economics |
School or tradition
|
New institutional economics |
Alma mater | Harvard University (PhD) University of Oxford (MA) North Dakota State (BA) |
Mançur Lloyd Olson Jr. (/ˈmænsər/;[1] 22 January 1932 – 19 February 1998) was an American economist and political scientist who taught at the University of Maryland, College Park. His most influential contributions were in institutional economics, and in the role which private property, taxation, public goods, collective action, and contract rights play in economic development.
Contents
Early life and education
Olson was born on January 22, 1932, in Grand Forks, North Dakota, to a family of Norwegian immigrants.[1][2][3] He grew up on a farm near Buxton, North Dakota, next to the state border with Climax, Minnesota.[4] Olson claimed that his given name, Mançur, was common throughout Scandinavian-immigrant communities in North America and was a variation of the Arabic name Mansoor.[1][3]
Olson graduated from North Dakota State University in 1954 and was a Rhodes Scholar at University College, Oxford until 1956, before earning a PhD in economics from Harvard in 1963.[1] He also served in the U.S. Air Force for two years from 1961 to 1963.[4]
Career
While serving in the U.S. Air Force, Olson became a lecturer in the Economics Department of the United States Air Force Academy from 1961 to 1963.[1] He then became an assistant professor at Princeton University in 1963.[4][5] Afterwards, he served as Deputy Assistant Secretary of Health, Education and Welfare for two years in Washington, D.C. In 1969, he left government and joined the economics department of the University of Maryland, College Park, where he remained until his death.[5]
Family life and death
Olson married his wife, Allison, in 1959, and the couple had three children.[2] At the time of his death, he was a resident of College Park, Maryland.[4]
On February 19, 1998, Olson, then 66 years of age, suddenly collapsed outside his office after returning from lunch. He never regained consciousness and died on the same day. The cause of death was later determined to be a heart attack.[4]
Legacy
Academic work
In his first book, The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups (1965), he theorized that what stimulates people to act in groups is incentive; members of large groups do not act in accordance with a common interest unless motivated by personal gain (economic, social, etc.). While small groups can act on shared objectives, large groups will not work towards shared objectives unless their individual members are sufficiently motivated.[6]
In 1982, he expanded the scope of his earlier work in an attempt to explain The Rise and Decline of Nations (1982). He argues that groups such as cotton farmers, steel producers, and labor unions have an incentive to form lobby groups and influence policies in their favor. These policies will tend to be protectionist, which will hurt economic growth; but because the benefits of such policies are concentrated, and their costs are diffused throughout the whole population, there will be little public resistance to them. As distributional coalitions accumulate, nations burdened by them will fall into economic decline. His work influenced the formulation of the Calmfors–Driffill hypothesis of collective bargaining.[7]
In his final book, Power and Prosperity (2000), Olson distinguished between the economic effects of different types of government, in particular, tyranny, anarchy, and democracy. Olson argued that under anarchy, a "roving bandit" only has the incentive to steal and destroy, whilst a "stationary bandit"—a tyrant—has an incentive to encourage some degree of economic success as he expects to remain in power long enough to benefit from that success. A stationary bandit thereby begins to take on the governmental function of protecting citizens and their property against roving bandits. In the move from roving to stationary bandits, Olson sees the seeds of civilization, paving the way, eventually for democracy, which by giving power to those who align with the wishes of the population, improves incentives for good government.[8] Olson's work on the roving vs. stationary bandits is influential in analysis of the political and economic order structured in warlord states and societies.[citation needed]
Policy work
To help bring his ideas to the attention of policymakers, Olson founded the Center for Institutional Reform in the Informal Sector ("IRIS Center"), funded by USAID (United States Agency for International Development). Based at the University of Maryland, the Center sought to supply an intellectual foundation for legal and economic reform projects carried out by USAID in formerly communist states that were attempting to make the transition to market-driven democratic governments governed by the rule of law. It was particularly active in East and Central Europe and the former Soviet Union.
The Center also became actively involved in projects in South America, Africa, and Asia, where it became a proponent of judicial independence. It sponsored the first conference on corruption in francophone Africa in the 1990s, when it was a very sensitive subject. The IRIS Center continued to operate after Olson's death, but was eventually folded into other programs at the University of Maryland.
To honor Olson's many contributions, the American Political Science Association established the Olson Award for the best PhD dissertation in Political Economy.[9] In 2013 the University of Maryland announced the creation of a new endowed professorship—the Mancur Olson Professor of Economics.[10] Maryland Professor of Economics Peter Murrell was the first Mancur Olson Professor.
Selected works
Books
- Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
- Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
- Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
- Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
- Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
- Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
Articles
- Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
- Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
- Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found. (with Martin C. McGuire)
- Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
See also
References
- ↑ 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
- ↑ 2.0 2.1 Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
- ↑ 3.0 3.1 Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
- ↑ 4.0 4.1 4.2 4.3 4.4 Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
- ↑ 5.0 5.1 Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
- ↑ Mancur Olson Jr., 1965, 2nd ed., 1971. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups, Harvard University Press, Description, Table of Contents, and preview.
- ↑ Mancur Olson, 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities, Yale University Press, 1982. Description, chapter-preview links, and review quotes.
- ↑ Mancur Olson, 2000. Power and Prosperity: Outgrowing Communist and Capitalist Dictatorships, Oxford University Press. Description and chapter-preview links. Foreign Affairs review.
- ↑ Organized Section 25: Mancur Olson Best Dissertation Award
- ↑ Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
External links
Wikiquote has quotations related to: Mancur Olson |
Lua error in package.lua at line 80: module 'strict' not found.
- Articles with short description
- Articles with hCards
- Articles with unsourced statements from October 2021
- Articles with invalid date parameter in template
- 1932 births
- 1998 deaths
- American people of Norwegian descent
- Economists from North Dakota
- New institutional economists
- American political scientists
- American Rhodes Scholars
- American social sciences writers
- Public choice theory
- University of Maryland, College Park faculty
- University of Maryland College of Behavioral and Social Sciences people
- People from Grand Forks, North Dakota
- Harvard University alumni
- Alumni of University College, Oxford
- North Dakota State University alumni
- 20th-century American economists
- 20th-century American writers